Sunday, March 3, 2019
International Diversification and the Market Value of New Product
journal of world(prenominal) way 17 (2011) 333347 Contents lists avail equal at ScienceDirect Journal of global Management International diversi? cation and the commercialiseplace valuate of tender harvesting gateway Chi-Feng Wang a,1, Li-Yu Chen b,? , Shao-Chi Chang c,2 a b c discussion section of assembly line Administ dimensionn, National Yunlin University of Science and engineering science, chinaw atomic number 18 Department of Management, Fo Guang University, Taiwan Institute of International Business, National Cheng Kung University, Taiwan article info phrase history Received 11 January 2011Received in revised form 31 March 2011 Accepted 31 March 2011 Available on delimitate 2 whitethorn 2011 Keywords International diversi? cation New merchandise introduction Technological cap great power merchandising aptitude shell register abstract Although preliminary studies on global diversification ar plentiful, they mainly focus on the outlet of global diversifi cation on over tot eachy firm performance, and the results argon mixed. This teach filtrates this line of re anticipate and explores the partake of remote diversification on reinvigorated crossing performance.Specifically, we ask if supranational diversification exempts the filiation commercialise reactions to rude(a) crossing introduction (NPI) proclamations. We find an inverted-U-shaped family amid transnational diversification and the announcement blow overs of NPIs, produceing that the food marketplace look upon of NPIs initially emends and then declines with change magnitude planetaryist diversification. The results overly show that intangible assets, such as scientific and merchandising capabilities, appointedly moderate the family among world-wide diversification and the market value of NPIs.Our study non hardly lavishlylights the immensity of considering both sides of unlike diversification in affecting investors assessments of corpora te b ar-ass convergence strategies, notwithstanding in addition shows the possibility of sexual capabilities in changing the fixed relationship among external diversification and the market value of innovative intersection points. 2011 Elsevier Inc. exclusively rights reserved. 1. Introduction According to the supposition of overseas direct investing (FDI) (Caves, 1996 Dunning, 1988 Hymer, 1976) and portfolio theory (Jacquillat and Solnik, 1978 Lessard, 1973, 1976 Solnik, 1974), foreign diversi? ation will lead to high ? rm value. However, existing studies exa excavation the tinct of external diversi? cation on ? rm performance fox yielded inconclusive results. The results on the relationship between foreign diversi? cation and ? rm performance has been rig to be positive (Delios and Beamish, 1999 Grant, 1987 Rugman et al. , 2008), disconfirming (Collins, 1990 Zaheer and Mosakowski, 1997), U-shaped (Capar and Kotabe, 2003 gaur and Kumar, 2009 Lu and Beamish, 20 01), inverted-U-shaped (Brock et al. , 2006 Garbe and Richter, 2009 Gomes and Ramaswamy, 1999 Hitt et al. 1997) and horizontal-S-shaped (Contractor et al. , 2003 Lu and Beamish, 2004 Ruigrok et al. , 2007). To better deduce the in? uence of external diversi? cation, we extend this line of research by studying the impact of supranational diversi? cation on b argon-ass produce performance. Speci? cally, we probe if multinational diversi? cation explains the line of work ? Corresponding actor at familiarize address Department of Management, Fo Guang University, No. 160, Linwei Rd. , Jiaosi, Yilan County 26247, Taiwan. Tel. + 886 3 9871000 23816. E-mail addresses emailprotected net. tw (C. -F. Wang), emailprotected fgu. edu. w (L. -Y. Chen), emailprotected ncku. edu. tw (S. -C. Chang). 1 Present address Department of Business Administ ration, National Yunlin University of Science and Technology, No. 123, University Road, region 3, Douliou, Yunlin 64002, Taiwan. Tel. + 886 5 53426015245. 2 Present address Institute of International Business, National Cheng Kung University, No. 1, University Road, 701, Tainan, Taiwan. Tel. + 886 6 275757553506. 1075-4253/$ larn front matter 2011 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved. doi10. 1016/j. intman. 2011. 03. 002 334 C. -F. Wang et al. / Journal of International Management 17 (2011) 333347 arket responses to vernal harvest-time introduction (NPI) announcements. NPIs are an important proportionality of innovation output. 3 Firms with the ability to introduce late products are signaled as those with the opportunity for diametricaliation and future earnings (Chaney et al. , 1991 Kleinschmidt and Cooper, 1991 Subramaniam and Venkatraman, 2001). In order to improve the performance of NPIs, m either ? rms are engaged in international diversi? cation activities (Kogut and Zander, 1993 Peng and Wang, 2000). foregoing studies capture documented that international diversi? cation comes with both bene? s and be (Con tractor et al. , 2003 Lu and Beamish, 2004 Ruigrok et al. , 2007). We stir that these bene? ts and cost might bring to pass both opportunities and challenges for ? rms to arrest in the raw-made products, and hence in? uence investors assessment of the new products introduced by ? rms. International diversi? cation whitethorn check positive effect on NPIs. For example, it allows ? rms to reach outside their domestic help boundaries, providing them with to a greater extent opportunities to relieve one and only(a)self new ideas in marges of the types of new products that drive out be developed (Hitt et al. , 1997). Internationally diversi? ed ? ms also consider better access to the resources nonmigratory in unknown countries that whitethorn be necessary for producing these new products (Craig and Douglas, 2000 Peng and Wang, 2000). Further much, international diversi? cation creates the bene? t of economies of weighing machine by ef? ciently supplement the initial i nvestments on new products over a broader market cup of tea (Subramaniam and Venkatraman, 2001). In spite of the bene? cial effects of international diversi? cation, we counsel that international diversi? cation may also entail disadvantages when it comes to introducing new products. For instance, cross-national distances ontogenesis the dif? ulty for internationally diversi? ed ? rms to carry scientific knowledge between countries. Differential environmental settings among countries might also constrain the ? rms ability to scoop and apply resources towards new product growing. In such cases, new products are packed to be less(prenominal) worthy for introducing ? rms with international diversi? cation activities. In addition to investigating the direct impact of international diversi? cation on the stock market reactions to NPI announcements, we postulate that investors assessments of the value of new products may depend on a ? ms internal capabilities. Extending previous research documenting the splendour of technological and selling capabilities in de lineining new product mastery (e. g. , Cooper and Kleinschmidt, 1987 Yeoh and Roth, 1999), we argue that both trade and technological capabilities assist in enhancing the bene? ts of international diversi? cation eon concurrently restricting its drawbacks with regard to the introduction of new products. We test our hypotheses by measuring the stock market responses to NPI announcements utilise the concomitant-study methodology framework.The events of NPI announcements are collected for the head 19972005. Under the assumption of the ef? cient markets hypothesis (Fama, 1970), NPI announcements go unanticipated information into ? nancial markets that may change the market value assessments of the announcing ? rms. In response to the new information, changes in stock expenses occur, which represent investors revision of their presentiment with regard to the net present value of a ? rms risk- familiarized expect specie ? ow ceded by the new products, or verbalize differently, the investors expectation of the wealth impact of NPIs.This motif is organized as get hitched withs Section 2 provides the theoretical empha coat and develops the hypotheses. Section 3 introduces the pattern and methodology. The empirical results are presented in Section 4. Finally, Section 5 contains the discussion and concluding remarks of this study. 2. Theoretical background and hypotheses International diversi? cation has been suggested by FDI theory and portfolio theory to provide ? rms with bene? ts ranging from the ability to realize photographic plate economies (Grant, 1987 Porter, 1986), the possibility to spread investment risks over different countries (Kim et al. 1993), the potential to good deal factor cost differentials across multiple locations (Kogut, 1985) and the opportunity to access resources resident in foreign countries (Hitt et al. , 1997). However, on that point is considerable theoretical evince that international diversi? cation comes with both bene? ts and costs. We suggest that that these bene? ts and costs that accompany foreign expansion may create both opportunities and challenges for ? rms in terms of education new products, and in that locationby affect the stock market reactions to NPI announcements.In this section, we re wad variant theoretical domains in order to identify the channels with which international diversi? cation might in? uence value creation for ? rms in the context of NPIs. 2. 1. Effects of international diversi? cation International diversi? cation provides some(prenominal)(prenominal) advantages towards developing new products. First, international diversi? cation offers opportunities for ? rms to gain new and divers(a) ideas from a variety of perspectives (Hitt et al. , 1997). Being exposed to heterogeneous customers, technology, cultures, and competitive practices, internationally diversi? d ? rms are able to learn from the experience in foreign operations to ? nd new solutions to bettering product design and improving the calibre of manufacturing know-how (Craig and Douglas, 2000). For example, the launch of a new cordless telephone by Sanyo, which had been even uped to better meet the phone exercise habits of Ameri canful consumers (Barkema and Vermeulen, 1998), consequently expand the companys gross sales in the U. S. market. 3 Prior studies take away used some(prenominal) ways to peak the performance of innovation, which includes R impregnation (Hill and Snell, 1988 Hitt et al. 1997), subjugate of NPIs (Cardinal and Opler, 1995 Hitt et al. , 1996) and number of patents (Francis and Smith, 1995). Though they boast provided blue-chip insights, the st institutionalises they developed have some limitations in capturing the true value of innovation (Chaney et al. , 1991 Schankerman and Pakes, 1986). For example, R loudness is more colligate to the input value of inno vation but does not directly measure the output value of innovation. Furthermore, numbers of NPIs or patents only measure the criterion of inventive output without considering the quality of innovation.As substantially, patent counts often represent a very noisy measure of the pro put up value of innovation because roughly patents are not worth anything. The measure used in our study allows us to directly measure the wealth effect of innovation, rather than only considering the quantity of inventive output as has been done in introductory studies. C. -F. Wang et al. / Journal of International Management 17 (2011) 333347 335 International diversi? cation also allows ? rms to gain access to resources that may only be lendable in foreign markets but not frequently obtainable in the home countries to develop new products (Peng and Wang, 2000).By tapping into the technological skills and knowledge that originates from another(prenominal) countries, multinational ? rms may be able to successfully increase their technological strength in developing new products (Hitt et al. , 1997 Kotabe, 1990 Peng and Wang, 2000 Subramaniam and Venkatraman, 2001). Moreover, international diversi? cation provides a ? rm with a wider national network, which helps increase its ability to effectively supplement technological resources and rationalize production processes. These economies of scale can enable the ? m to obtain high(prenominal) returns from new product innovations (Bartlett and Ghoshal, 1989 Kogut, 1985). Furthermore, the broader market outlets easy to new products create higher(prenominal) returns on the sunk costs of innovative pass awaying (Subramaniam and Venkatraman, 2001), while cash ? ows generated from large-scale foreign operations provide ? rms with the resources needed for extra investment in new product outgrowth (Kobrin, 1991 Kotabe, 1990). Notwithstanding the above bene? ts, international diversi? cation can bring challenges to the development o f new products. The ? rst challenge comes from the dif? ulty in transferring technological knowledge between countries. The more countries at heart which the ? rm operates, the larger geographic distance the technological know-how has to be transferred, and the less effective the ? rm will be in developing new products. Furthermore, with increasing diversi? cation, the differences in cultural, economic and technological settings among the countries increase. These differences reduce the effectiveness in assimilating and applying the technological knowledge that is critical for new product development (Chang and Wang, 2007 Hitt et al. 1997) while knowledge diversity can create greater learning value (Inkpen, 2000), differences in knowledge does not guarantee successful learning (Bowman and Helfat, 2001 Chang and Singh, 2000 Szulanski and Winter, 2002). In addition, arguments from the economic law of change magnitude returns suggest that the higher degree of international diversi? cation a ? rm is involved in, the more liable(predicate) it is to be entering markets whose borderline contributions are relatively lowly (Contractor et al. , 2003). beyond a authorized point, aft(prenominal)ward already having expanded into the virtually advantageous markets, the ? m is left with minor or peripheral foreign markets whose resources for and cash ? ow from new product development will exhibit diminishing returns. By drawing on various theoretical perspectives, the above discussions suggest that international diversi? cation not only create opportunities but also impose barriers to the value creation provided by new product innovation. With moderate aims of international diversi? cation, ? rms can capitalize on valuable bene? ts of knowledge learning, resource access and production ef? ciency in producing new products.At the aforesaid(prenominal) time, economic pro? ts rise as the ? xed costs of new product development are spread across more markets (Kogut, 1 985 Porter, 1986). However, ? rms that expand internationally beyond an optimal level may ? nd that the costs of international diversi? cation eventually exceed the bene? ts. Firms at this stage often enter countries that are more geographically and culturally dissimilar, which increases the dif? culties of transferring technological knowledge between countries. The value of new product innovation may also exhibit diminishing returns when international diversi? ation is increased beyond the optimal level. Based on the above, this study proposes a non- one-dimensional and inverted-U-shaped relationship between international diversi? cation and the stock market reactions to NPI announcements, suggesting that the market value of NPIs is pass judgment to improve with increasing international diversi? cation at disgrace levels of international diversi? cation and then decline with increasing international diversi? cation at higher levels of international diversi? cation. For these reas ons, we propose our ? rst hypothesis as follows Hypothesis 1.The relationship between international diversi? cation and the stock market reactions to NPI announcements is inverted-U-shaped, with a positive slope at lower levels of international diversi? cation and minus at higher levels of international diversi? cation. We go for event-study methodology to capture the valuation effect of corporate new product strategies. This climb up not only permits direct investigation of changes in announcing ? rms stockholder value, but is also suited to conduct cross-sectional analysis of the strategies underlying the value creation or destruction (Reuer, 2001).Applying event-study methodology to NPIs also facilitates comparisons with previous studies on other corporate major strategic events. 4 2. 2. fundamental interaction effects of intangible assets and international diversi? cation Although our theoretical framework should hold for all ? rms, the effect of international diversi? catio n on new product performance may depend on ? rms intangible assets. Scholars in international stage business have shown that multinational ? rms with greater marketing and technological capabilities may receive higher returns from international expansion (Kotabe et al. , 2002 Lu andBeamish, 2004). other(a) researchers also document the grandeur of marketing and technological capabilities in the success of new products (e. g. , Cooper and Kleinschmidt, 1987 Danneels, 2002 Krasnikov and Jayachandran, 2008 Moorman and Slotegraaf, 1999 Yeoh and Roth, 1999). We desexualize advances in linking these two streams of study by investigating the moderating effect 4 Previous studies have used event-study methodology to test the wealth effect of major corporate events, such as diversi? cation (Doukas and Lang, 2003 Hoskisson et al. , 1991), divestitures (Benou et al. , 2008), alliances (Das et al. 1998 Kale et al. , 2002), restrictive change (Bowman and Navissi, 2003), NPIs (Chaney et al. , 1991 Chen, 2008 Kelm et al. , 1995), R expenditures (Szewczyk et al. , 1996), and patents (Austin, 1993). 336 C. -F. Wang et al. / Journal of International Management 17 (2011) 333347 of internal capabilities on the association between international diversi? cation and the stock market reactions to NPI announcements. We suggest that internationally diversi? ed ? rms that have greater marketing and technological capabilities are more able to extract the bene? ts and reduce the costs of international diversi? ation, resulting in higher returns from NPI announcements. Each moderating effect is discussed unconditionally below. marketing energy is related to a ? rms ability to acquire external knowledge by marrow of the processes of gathering, find outing, and using market information (Day, 1994). Though international diversi? cation gives ? rms opportunities to access new knowledge, ? rms that do not have ability to identify customers needs and to understand the factors that in? uence consumer choice behavior will not be able to achieve better targeting and positioning of its products.Therefore, ? rms that have invested in developing their marketing efficiency are more able to integrate the information on consumer needs in diverse markets into new product designs, and indeed generate higher returns from the new products (Dutta et al. , 1999). In addition, marketing qualification is re? ected in a ? rms ability to differentiate its products from those of competitors (Kotabe et al. , 2002). A higher level of product differentiation allows a ? rm to charge higher damages for its new products (Day, 1994 Yeoh and Roth, 1999). Furthermore, ? ms that spend more money on announce and promoting their products are more probably to build successful brands, which are essential to building awareness, reducing the sensed risk that consumers associate with new products, and ? nally increasing the adoption rate of new products introduced (Chandy and Tellis, 2000 Do wling and Staelin, 1994 Sorescu et al. , 2003). This is particularly important for ? rms that are completely new to foreign customers (Helsen et al. , 1993 Srivastava et al. , 1998). Consequently, we expect that NPIs are expected to be more worthwhile for internationally diversi? d ? rms with greater marketing capabilities, leadership to Hypothesis 2 Hypothesis 2. Marketing capacitance will positively moderate the relationship between international diversi? cation and the stock market reactions to NPI announcements. As mentioned, technological capacity is also likely to moderate the effect of international diversi? cation on new product development. Technology capability might represent a ? rms ability to absorb external knowledge (Penner-Hahn and Shaver, 2005 Tsai, 2001). A ? rm may be able to access certain new knowledge through international diversi? ation, but without the capacity to absorb such knowledge a ? rm may not enhance its capabilities within new product innovation. S ince knowledge gained from international markets is often tacit and socially complex (Zahra and Hayton, 2008), ? rms that have established a capability in a particular research skill are better able to interpret and assess the knowledge in that area. Technological capability also refers to a ? rms ability to apply knowledge gained from foreign markets to commercial ends (Krasnikov and Jayachandran, 2008 Moorman and Slotegraaf, 1999).Kotabe et al. (2002) have stated that ? rms with greater technological capabilities are more capable of ? nding better product design solutions. The technical risks in developing new products are more likely to be reduced for such ? rms (Kelm et al. , 1995). Furthermore, ? rms with greater technological capability are more able to lower production costs by improving manufacturing processes. Moreover, technological capability helps ? rms to speed up the product development process and satisfy the market more quickly (Rabino and Moskowitz, 1981). Thus, ? m s that have greater technological capabilities are more likely to enhance their receiptss in international markets by providing those markets with new products of better quality. Meanwhile, ? rms that leverage their technological capabilities in the greater scope of the global market may enjoy the bene? ts of economies of scale inherent in the innovation process. As a result, we expect that NPIs are more worthwhile for internationally diversi? ed ? rms with greater technological capabilities, leading to Hypothesis 3 Hypothesis 3. Technological capability will positively moderate the relationship between international diversi? ation and the stock market reactions to NPI announcements. 3. exemplar and methodology 3. 1. Sample design We test our hypotheses using a experiment of NPI announcement events. We collect the sample information on ? rms listed on every the New York Stock alter (NYSE) or the American Stock Exchange (AMEX) from the Dow Jones News Retrieval Service (DJNRS) infobase, which provides news-service articles and selected stories from the Wall Street Journal, Dow Jones News Wire, and Barrons. We use the words and phrases commonly used to describe NPIs as keys for a database search routine.Examples are introduce, new product, unveil, launch, received approval, to market, test market, begin selling, along with other pertinent words and phrases. When a repeat NPI announcement from a ? rm is ground in a different publication, the announcement that has the earliest date is elect as it is the earliest date when the information about the NPI is publicly available (Chaney et al. , 1991 Chen, 2008 Kelm et al. , 1995). The sample degree is from January 1997 to December 2005. Four criteria are used when selecting ? rms for our sample (1) the announcing ? rms should not have other announcements ? e twenty-four hour periods in the lead and after the initial announcement date in order to avoid any confounding events that could distort the measurement of the valuation effects (2) nonchalant stock return information must be available from the Center for enquiry in Security Prices (CRSP), with a minimum of 50 daily returns in the estimation period (3) companies ? nancial information must be available from the COMPUSTAT ? les and (4) since we insufficiency to test the effect of international diversi? cation, only those ? rms with foreign sales data available from the COMPUSTAT ? les are included. C. -F. Wang et al. Journal of International Management 17 (2011) 333347 337 avocation these procedures, we collect a ? nal sample comprising 3061 new product announcements made by 531 ? rms in 57 industries based on the two-digit Standard industrial Classi? cation ( localise) codes. 5 plank 1 taradiddles the dispersal of the sample by twelvemonth and exertion. Our data shows no obvious cluster by time period. In 2004, on that point are 530 announcements, account for 17. 32% of the total. Observations are nearly evenly distributed t hrough the remaining days. However, our sample shows certain levels of soaking up in speci? c industries.The largest concentration comes from electrical equipment (33. 61%), reckoner equipment (18. 09%), electro-medical instruments (9. 38%), and business go (e. g. , computer programming and the software exertion) (7. 19%). These third broad categories constitute nearly 70% of the total sample. As suggested by Chaney et al. (1991), this result is expected since incomplete the investment opportunities nor their valuation should be random across industries. 3. 2. Measuring the stock market responses to new product announcements We employ the event study methodology to examine the stock price responses to the announcements of NPIs. This approach has been widely used in the management, accounting, economics and ? nance disciplines to examine the impact of ? rm-speci? c events on ? rm value. The event study approach suggests that, in an ef? cient capital market, the market will a djust and result in returns different from those that are normally expected if the NPI announcement has unexpected information content (Hoskisson et al. , 1991). We use the market model suggested by Brown and Warner (1985) to estimate the kinky returns to NPI announcements. This model captures a ? rms stock price change after adjusting for general market-wide factors and the ? ms systematic risk (Bowman, 1983 Brown, 1989 Brown and Warner, 1980, 1985). The irregular return for ? rm i on day t, ARit, is computed by ARit = Rit ? E? Rit = It ? 1 ? where Rit is ? rm is actual returns on day t, and It ? 1 represents the information set available to the market about the ? rm at time t ? 1. The expected return for ? rm i on day t is estimated by E? Rit = It ? 1 ? = ? i + ? i Rmt where Rmt is the return for the market portfolio on day t, ? i is the intercept, and ? i measures the risk or sensitivity of the ? rms returns relative to the market portfolio. We de? e Day 0 (t = 0) as the initi al announcement date. We use the value-weighted CRSP forefinger as the proxy for the market portfolio. The parameters ? i and ? i are estimated using data for the period of 200 to 60 days before the initial announcement date. The two-day accumulative abnormal returns, auto (? 1, 0), are estimated by summing the daily abnormal returns over the window period of days ? 1 and 0. The every bit weighted cross-sectional add up abnormal returns on ? event day t, ARt , is further calculated by 1N ? ARt = ? ARit N i=1 where N is the total number of sample NPIs. The cumulative amount abnormal return over the period (? , 0) is similarly de? ned. 3. 3. Measuring international diversi? cation We use the noise index number to estimate international diversi? cation. 7 The entropy measure of international diversi? cation is de? ned as ? Pi* ln(1/Pi), where Pi is the percentage of sales in geographic segment i, and ln(1/Pi) is the weight of each geographic segment. This measure thus considers both the number of geographic segments in which a ? rm operates and the relative importance of sales contributed by each geographic segment. 5 For the labor classi? cation, we follow Hitt et al. (1997) and use the our-digit correct codes as the indicator of the industry or business segment that a ? rm operates. Therefore, two variables in this study, namely product diversi? cation and industry R&D earnestness, are estimated basing on the four-digit SIC codes. However, for the sake of brevity, we report the sample distribution by industry on the basis of the two-digit SIC codes. 6 Other performance measures of new product strategies that are most commonly used in previous studies include return on assets, return on sales, return on equity, return on investment and pro? t margin (e. g. , Li and Atuahene-Gima, 2001 Moorman, 1995).However, these accounting measures have several limitations in measuring new product performance (Chang and Wang, 2007 Kalyanaram et al. , 1995 Pauwels et al. , 2004). For example, the differences in accounting policies across ? rms make performance comparisons dif? cult. These measures are also not risk-adjusted as they do not consider business risks associated with individual ? rms when measuring performance, and they are based on historical accounting data and thus may not adequately re? ect future expected revenue streams resulting from the new products. More importantly, these measures re? ect aggregate ? m performance, devising it more dif? cult to directly link them to the effect of speci? c new product introductions. Due to these limitations we employ an event study methodology in order to examine stock price responses to announcements of NPIs. This method captures the ? rms stock price change after adjusting for the ? rms systematic risk (Bowman, 1983 Brown, 1989 Brown and Warner, 1980, 1985), as well as re? ects investors expectations of a ? rms future cash ? ow related to this new product (Chaney et al. , 1991 Chen, 2008 Chen et al. , 2002 Kelm et al. , 1995). 7 Previous studies have used several proxies of international diversi? ation. The most commonly used measures are the ratio of foreign sales to total sales (Grant, 1987 Tallman and Li, 1996), the ratio of foreign assets to total assets (Daniels and Bracker, 1989 Ramaswamy, 1995), numbers of foreign countries in which a ? rm has subsidiaries (Delios and Beamish, 1999 Tallman and Li, 1996) or a composite index encompassing these three dimensions (Gomes and Ramaswamy, 1999 Sullivan, 1994). However, these measures only capture the extent but not the distribution of international diversi? cation. In this study, we follow Hitt et al. (1997) and use the entropy measure of international diversi? ation to account for the extent of sales in global markets and their weighting. C. -F. Wang et al. / Journal of International Management 17 (2011) 333347 338 Table 1 Distribution of new product introduction. Panel A. Sample distribution by year class Number o f announcements Percent of sample (%) 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 Total 354 279 370 313 232 247 391 530 345 3061 11. 56 9. 11 12. 08 10. 22 7. 58 8. 07 12. 77 17. 32 11. 30 100. 00 Panel B. Sample distribution by industry Two-digit SIC code Industry group 01 12 13 15 16 17 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 33 34 Agricultural production cropsCoal mining Oil and gas extraction Building construction general contractors atrocious construction other than building construction contractors Construction special trade contractors Food and kindred products Tobacco products Textile mill products Apparel, ? nished prdcts from fabrics and similar materials ram down and wood products, except furniture Furniture and ? xtures Paper and ally products Printing, publishing, and allied industries Chemicals and allied products Petroleum re? ning and related industries Rubber and miscellaneous plastics products lather and leather products Primary metal industriesFabricated metal pr oducts, except machinery and theodolite equipment Industrial and commercial machinery and computer equipment Electronic and other electrical equipment and components, except computer equipment Transportation equipment Measuring, analyzing, and controlling instruments photographic, medical and optical goods Miscellaneous manufacturing industries Railroad transportation Motor freight transportation and warehousing Transportation by air Pipelines, except internal gas Transportation services Communications Electric, gas, and hygienical services Wholesale trade durable goods Wholesale trade non-durable goodsBuilding materials, hardware, garden supply, and mobile home dealers General merchandise stores Food stores Apparel and participator stores Home furniture, furnishings, and equipment stores Eating and drinking places Miscellaneous retail Depository institutions Non-depository reliance institutions Security and commodity brokers, dealers, exchanges, and services Insurance carriers Insurance agents, brokers, and service true(a) estate Holding and other investment of? ces Hotels, rooming houses, camps, and other lodging places ad hominem services 35 36 37 38 39 40 42 45 46 47 48 49 50 51 52 53 54 56 57 58 59 60 61 62 63 64 65 67 0 72 Number of announcements Percent of sample (%) 1 1 8 1 1 1 28 4 2 2 3 6 13 76 118 2 9 2 23 21 0. 03 0. 03 0. 26 0. 03 0. 03 0. 03 0. 91 0. 13 0. 07 0. 07 0. 10 0. 20 0. 42 2. 48 3. 85 0. 07 0. 29 0. 07 0. 75 0. 69 554 1029 18. 09 33. 61 72 287 2. 35 9. 38 41 4 2 144 1 1 120 20 19 10 2 3 3 8 6 14 13 2 18 17 34 5 3 9 6 6 1. 34 0. 13 0. 07 4. 70 0. 03 0. 03 3. 92 0. 65 0. 62 0. 33 0. 07 0. 10 0. 10 0. 26 0. 20 0. 46 0. 42 0. 07 0. 59 0. 56 1. 11 0. 16 0. 10 0. 29 0. 20 0. 20 C. -F. Wang et al. / Journal of International Management 17 (2011) 333347 339 Table 1 (continued) Panel B. Sample distribution by industryTwo-digit SIC code Industry group 73 78 79 80 82 87 Business services Motion pictures Amusement and deviation services Heal th services Educational services Engineering, accounting, research, management, and related services Nonclassi? able establishments 99 Total Number of announcements Percent of sample (%) 220 13 4 2 1 10 7. 19 0. 42 0. 13 0. 07 0. 03 0. 33 36 3061 1. 18 100. 00 As data is not available at the country level, we use sales of regional markets to measure international diversity (as used by e. g. , Hirsch and Lev, 1971 Hitt et al. , 1997 Miller and Pras, 1980). Following Hitt et al. 1997), we group foreign markets into four regions based on economic and political conditions Africa, Asia and the Paci? c, Europe, and the Americas. Although not perfect, this approach allows us to focus on between-market heterogeneity (Kim et al. , 1989). The international market sales data are from the COMPUSTAT geographic segment tapes for the ? scal year forego the announcements. 8 3. 4. Measuring intangible assets We measure marketing capability as the average marketing rapture (the ratio of advertiseme nt expenditures to net sales) for the three ? scal years prior to the announcements. 9 We suggest that ? ms who invest more in marketing activities are considered to have superior marketing capabilities. We measure technological capability as the average R&D intensity (the ratio of R&D expenditures to net sales) for the three ? scal years prior to the announcements. We suggest that ? rms outspending their competitors in R&D are considered to have greater technological capabilities. We scale the measures of ? rm capabilities by ? rm size in order to agree that the capability measure does not merely re? ect higher levels of ? nancial resources of large-scaled ? rms (following Moorman and Slotegraaf, 1999). 3. 5. Other variablesOther potential variables that could affect the value of NPIs are controlled. The ? rst is ? rm size, mensural by the inwrought logarithm of total sales of the announcing ? rm for the ? scal year previous the announcement (following Kotabe et al. , 2002 Lu an d Beamish, 2004). We next control for a ? rms leverage ratio, measured as the ratio of total debt to total assets for the ? scal year prior to the announcement (following Chen et al. , 2002 Chen, 2008). We also control for the degree of product diversi? cation for the ? scal year preceding the announcement. Product diversi? cation is measured by the entropy index (? Pi * ln(1/Pi), where Pi is the percentage of ? rm sales in business segment i, and ln(1/Pi) is the weight of each segment). Following Hitt et al. (1997), we de? ne business segments as those having the same four-digit SIC codes. The product-speci? c effects are also controlled. This is necessary as some researchers have suggested that high-newness products are expected to create better opportunities for product differentiation and competitive advantage (Kleinschmidt and Cooper, 1991 Meyer and Roberts, 1986), and as such, high-newness products should receive a larger market value than updates of existing products.Further more, scholars have argued that ? rms introducing multiple products are more competitive in the product market and seize more market share than those announcing iodin products. This implies that ? rms announcing multipleproducts announcers may book much of the bene? ts associated with new products, and are thus expected to experience a larger increase in market value than those announcing a single product (Acs and Audretsch, 1988 Hendricks and Singhal, 1997). Moreover, researchers have documented that the ? rst to introduce a new product in the marketplace usually enjoys ? st-mover advantages stemming from the creation of entry barriers and switching costs, and from high consumer recognition and preference to the ? rst product (Jovanovic and MacDonald, 1994 Lee et al. , 2000). Therefore, ? rst-moving ? rms are predicted to gain a higher announcement return at the time of NPIs than followers do. The aforementioned(prenominal) ? rms that introduce high-newness and multiple products or ? rms that are the ? rst to introduce new products are suggested to obtain sustained competitive advantage. This argument corresponds to Williamson (1999) that ? ms getting forth of their competitors by providing multiple and new technology, products and business solutions have more opportunities to ensure lasting sales growth. We identify these product announcement types by using structural content analysis on the news content (as in Chaney et al. , 1991 Lee et al. , 2000 Firth and Narayanan, 1996). Based on the analysis of the news content, we create three dummy variables NEWNESS, MULTIPLE and TIME. 8 The main reason for using data one year before the announcements is to capture the most recent impact of a ? ms attributes on the market reactions to new product introductions. Several independent variables are measured by the data one year preceding the announcements, including international diversi? cation, ? rm size, debt-to-asset ratio, product diversi? cation and two indust ry sector dummy variables. 9 Since the values of advertising and R&D expenditures tend to ? uctuate substantially from year to year, we use the 3-year average values of advertising intensity, R&D intensity and industry R&D intensity to reduce the chance that a random and extreme value in one year disproportionately in? ences our measure of intangible assets. 340 C. -F. Wang et al. / Journal of International Management 17 (2011) 333347 NEWNESS equals one if the product is highly innovative, and zero if it is an update or an enhancement of an existing product (as in Chaney et al. , 1991 Chen, 2008). MULTIPLE equals one for multiple-products announced concurrently by a ? rm, and zero for single announcements (as in Chaney et al. , 1991 Chen, et al. , 2002). TIME equals one if the announcing ? rm is the ? rst mover, and zero otherwise (as in Lee et al. , 2000 Chen, 2008).Finally, we consider two industry-related factors. The ? rst is the technological opportunity of the industry in wh ich the announcing ? rms operate. Chaney et al. (1991) asserted that the valuation effect of NPIs is higher for ? rms in more technologically based industries, as they are considered to have more innovation opportunities and greater potential for future growth. In contrast, Kelm et al. (1995) found that investors respond positively to new product announcements by ? rms in less-technology-intensive industries because new product announcements by these ? rms are relatively nexpected by investors. Technological opportunities at the industry level are measured by the average industry R&D intensity (the average values of R&D expenditures divided by net sales for all ? rms in the same four-digit SIC industry) for the three ? scal years prior to the announcements (following Chan et al. , 1990 Kelm et al. , 1995). In addition, we control for the industry-speci? c effect with two dummy variables MANUFACTURING and dish. MANUFACTURING equals one for announcing ? rms in manufacturing industrie s, and zero otherwise. SERVICE equals one for announcing ? ms in service industries, and zero otherwise. This is done as several studies have argued that the effect of internationality on performance for manufacturing ? rms is different from that for service ? rms (Capar and Kotabe, 2003 Contractor et al. , 2003). We therefore separate the sample ? rms into service, manufacturing and other industries fit in to 2-digit SIC codes and apply two industry dummies to control for the industry-speci? c effects. Table 2 presents the means, standard deviations, and correlations for all variables for the sample of NPI announcements. 4. Empirical resultsTable 3 provides estimates of abnormal returns around the announcement date and the surrounding days. The results show that innovations such as NPIs are perceived by investors as value-increasing activities. For the two-day announcement period cumulative abnormal returns, railway car (? 1, 0), the new product announcers experience a positive cu mulative average abnormal return of 0. 194%, signi? monger at the 1% con? dence level. No signi? angle abnormal returns are observed preceding and following the announcement period. As a result, we use simple machine (? 1, 0) as the dependent variable in the following regression analysis.Our results are accordant with prior studies (e. g. , Chaney et al. , 1991 Chen, 2008 Chen et al. , 2002 Kelm et al. , 1995). Table 4 reports the regression results with the dependent variable CAR (? 1, 0). We present the results without centering the variables in the ? rst ? ve models, and results with centering the variables on their means in the latter ? ve models. 10 mannequins 1 and 6 are service line models that include only the control variables and two measures of intangible assets. Among the control variables, leverage ratio is found to be positively associated with CAR (? 1, 0), though insigni? cant in some models.This result suggests that higher levels of debt lower the expected cost s of free cash ? ow (Jensen, 1986), and new products announced by ? rms with a higher leverage ratio are therefore perceived as more worthwhile. Of the two ? rm-speci? c assets variables, both R&D and advertising intensities have a signi? cant and positive impact in most models. Moreover, industry R&D intensity is found to be signi? cantly negatively associated with CAR (? 1, 0). This result suggests that investors respond positively to new product announcements by ? rms in less technology-intensive industries because new product announcements by these ? ms are relatively unexpected by investors (Kelm et al. , 1995). Other control variables are not found to have signi? cant explanatory power in terms of the fluctuation in announcement abnormal returns. In model 2 (7), we test the impact of international diversi? cation on the stock market reactions to NPI announcements by including the linear and squared terms of international diversi? cation. We ? nd our Hypothesis 1 is potently supported, as CAR (? 1, 0) is positively related to the linear term of international diversi? cation and then negatively associated to the squared term of international diversi? cation.This result suggests an inverted-U-shaped relationship between international diversi? cation and the market value of NPIs. moldings 3 (8), 4 (9) and 5 (10) test the moderating effects of intangible assets by including the interaction term of international diversi? cation and advertising intensity and the interaction term of international diversi? cation and R&D intensity. 11 Model 3 (8) tests the interaction effect between international diversi? cation and marketing capability. The statistically signi? cant and positive coef? cient of the interaction term suggests that the market value of NPIs increases when internationally diversi? d ? rms have greater marketing capacities. Thus, Hypothesis 2 is supported. Model 4 (9) tests the interaction effect between international diversi? cation and technologic al capability. We also ? nd a statistically signi? cant and positive coef? cient of the interaction term. Thus, Hypothesis 3 is supported. To test the robustness of these ? ndings, we simultaneously include the interaction of international diversi? cation and advertising intensity and the interaction of international diversi? cation and R&D intensity in model 5 (10). Results remain unchanged to those in models 3 (8) and 4 (9).It is noted that the main effects between international diversi? cation and the abnormal returns of NPIs remain robust in all models with the addition of the interaction terms. To gain further insights into our ? ndings, we construct Figs. 1 and 2 by drawing on the results of models 3 and 4. We use CAR (? 1, 0) as the measurement of market value of NPIs. When illustrating the impact of advertising intensity (R&D intensity) and 10 Since some variables are constructed from other variables, we follow Aiken and West (1991) by subtracting each variable from its mean value in the sample to defame their collinearity. 11To test the robustness of our conclusion, we re-examine the regression analysis by incorporating the interaction of quadratic terms of international diversi? cation and intangible asset proxies. Our conclusions remain unchanged. Variables a Mean s. d. Min Max 1. Two-day announcementperiod abnormal return(%)a 2. International diversi? cation 3. publicise intensity 4. R&D intensity 5. Product diversi? cation 6. Firm size b 7. Debt-to-asset ratio 8. Newness 9. Multiple 10. Time 11. Industry R&D intensity 12. Service industry 13. Manufacturing industry 0. 194 0. 037 ? 0. 242 0. 230 0. 653 0. 012 0. 081 0. 816 8. 541 0. 00 0. 827 0. 302 0. 359 0. 236 0. 236 0. 748 0. 424 0. 022 0. 148 0. 659 1. 860 0. 149 0. 379 0. 459 0. 480 0. 390 0. 425 0. 434 0. 000 0. 000 0. 000 0. 000 ? 0. 781 0. 000 0. 000 0. 000 0. 000 0. 000 0. 000 0. 000 1. 382 0. 317 4. 696 2. 533 12. 060 1. 099 1. 000 1. 000 1. 000 2. 334 1. 000 1. 000 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 1. 00 0 ? 0. 033* 1. 000 0. 102*** ? 0. 071*** 1. 000 ? 0. 004 ? 0. 042** ? 0. 016 1. 000 0. 149*** 0. 092*** ? 0. 158*** 0. 399*** 1. 000 ? 0. 111*** 0. 001 ? 0. 090*** 0. 052*** 0. 075*** 1. 000 0. 036** ? 0. 002 0. 010 ? 0. 003 0. 027 ? 0. 021 1. 000 9 0. 076*** 0. 050*** 0. 015 ? 0. 024 0. 016 ? 0. 100*** 0. 33* 1. 000 The two-day period (? 1,0) abnormal return is estimated by summing up abnormal returns from the day before (day ? 1) to the announcement date (day 0). Firm size is measured by the natural logarithm of net sales. ***p b 0. 01, **pb0. 05, *pb0. 1. b 10 11 12 13 0. 045** ? 0. 022 0. 056*** 0. 039** 0. 024 ? 0. 050*** 0. 170*** ? 0. 040** 1. 000 0. 257*** ? 0. 083*** 0. 252*** ? 0. 042** ? 0. 188*** ? 0. 098*** 0. 031* 0. 039** 0. 055*** 1. 000 ? 0. 382*** 0. 000 ? 0. 137*** ? 0. 206*** ? 0. 020 0. 199*** ? 0. 007 ? 0. 147*** ? 0. 064*** ? 0. 151*** 1. 000 0. 342*** 0. 017 0. 143*** 0. 151*** ? 0. 017 ? 0. 222*** . 009 0. 147*** 0. 068*** 0. 166*** ? 0. 960*** 1. 000 C. -F. Wang et al. / Journal of International Management 17 (2011) 333347 Table 2 Descriptive statistics and correlations. 341 342 C. -F. Wang et al. / Journal of International Management 17 (2011) 333347 Table 3 Abnormal returns for new product introduction announcements. Event day Mean AR (%) t-statistic ? 10 ?9 ?8 ?7 ?6 ?5 ?4 ?3 ?2 ?1 0 ? 1,0 +1 +2 +3 +4 +5 +6 +7 +8 +9 + 10 ? 0. 023 ? 0. 005 0. 025 ? 0. 016 ? 0. 025 ? 0. 005 0. 047 0. 001 ? 0. 039 0. 093 0. 101 0. 194 ? 0. 038 0. 058 0. 081 ? 0. 056 0. 027 ? 0. 073 ? 0. 055 0. 053 ? 0. 025 ? 0. 054 ? 0. 450 0. 092 0. 471 ? 0. 309 ? 0. 477 ? 0. 099 0. 888 0. 003 ? 0. 731 1. 918* 2. 038** 2. 885*** ? 0. 756 1. 086 1. 329 ? 1. 138 0. 529 ? 1. 403 ? 1. 078 1. 118 ? 0. 471 ? 0. 972 (0. 653) (0. 927) (0. 638) (0. 758) (0. 633) (0. 921) (0. 375) (0. 998) (0. 465) (0. 055) (0. 042) (0. 004) (0. 450) (0. 278) (0. 184) (0. 255) (0. 597) (0. 161) (0. 281) (0. 264) (0. 638) (0. 331) ***p b 0. 01, **p b 0. 05. Values in parentheses are p-values. in ternational diversi? cation on CAR (? 1, 0), we hold other control variables at the average level. If the control variables are dummy ones, we substitute these variables with their modes. 2 Both ? gures provide supportive evidence for our hypotheses. First, the relationship between international diversi? cation and the market value of NPIs is found to be inverted-U-shaped, with the slope positive at lower levels of international diversi? cation but negative at higher levels of international diversi? cation. For example, in Fig. 1, for ? rms with no marketing capability, at the initial stage, there is a positive impact on the market value of NPIs with an increase of 0. 62% in CAR (? 1, 0) when the level of international diversi? cation increases from zero to 0. 8. Beyond this threshold of 0. , a higher level of international diversi? cation is associated with a decreasing CAR (? 1, 0). In Fig. 2, for ? rms with no technological capability, there is a positive impact on the market val ue of NPIs with an increase of 0. 63% in CAR (? 1, 0) when the level of international diversi? cation increases from zero to 0. 8. Beyond this point, more international diversi? cation results in lower market values of NPIs. In addition, these graphs illustrate the performance differences across ? rms with different levels of intangible assets. For example, in Fig. 1, for a ? rm with a degree of international diversi? cation of 0. and a level of marketing capability of 0. 3, there is an expected CAR (? 1, 0) that is almost 0. 89% higher than that for a ? rm at the same level of international diversi? cation but with the marketing capability of 0. 1 at a degree of international diversi? cation of 1. 2, there is an expected improvement in CAR (? 1, 0) of 3. 25% when the level of marketing capability increases from 0. 1 to 0. 3. The same procedure can be used to explain the moderating effect of technological capability. In Fig. 2, for a ? rm with a level of international diversi? catio n of 0. 4 and a level of technology capability of 1. , there is an expected CAR (? 1, 0) that is 2. 09% higher than that for a ? rm at the same level of international diversi? cation but with the technological capability of 0. 4 at a degree of international diversi? cation of 1. 2, there is an expected improvement in CAR (? 1, 0) of 4. 92% when the technology capability of a ? rm increases from 0. 4 to 1. 6. 5. Discussion and conclusions This paper examines the importance of international diversi? cation in explaining the stock market reactions to NPI announcements. Using NPI announcements from the period 19972005, we found an inverted-U-shaped relationship between international diversi? ation and the market value of NPIs, with a slope positive at lower levels of international diversi? cation but negative at higher levels of international diversi? cation. This relationship is moderated by the intangible assets have by internationally diversi? ed ? rms. We ? nd that announcing ? rms with greater technological and/or marketing capabilities achieve higher abnormal returns from NPIs. The main effects of the international diversi? cation variables still hold after the inclusion of these moderating factors. In view of recent research having suggested a sigmoid performance effect of internationalization (Contractor et al. 2003 Lu and Beamish, 2004), we test our hypotheses in the framework of an S-shaped relationship by simultaneously adding linear, squared and cubed terms of international diversi? cation in the regression. However, our sample does not reveal the S-shaped association between international diversi? cation and the market value of NPI. 12 The equations for the graphs presented in Figs. 1 and 2 are as follows, respectively CAR (? 1, 0) = ? 0. 0037 + 0. 0157 * ID ? 0. 0099 * ID2 ? 0. 0147 * AD + 0. 1476 * ID * AD and CAR (? 1, 0) = ? 0. 0049 + 0. 0168 * ID ? 0. 0112 * ID2 + 0. 0056 * RD + 0. 295 * ID * RD, where ID = international diversi? cation ID2 = In ternational diversi? cation squared AD = advertising intensity RD = R&D intensity. C. -F. Wang et al. / Journal of International Management 17 (2011) 333347 343 Table 4 Regression analysis of new product introduction on international diversi? cation. Un-centered results Centered results Independent variables Model 1 Model 2 Intercept ? 0. 0005 (? 0. 072) ? 0. 0042 ? 0. 0017 ? 0. 0037 ? 0. 0009 (? 0. 591) (? 0. 233) (? 0. 525) (? 0. 122) 0. 0178 0. 0157 0. 0168 0. 0143 (3. 156)*** (2. 737)*** (2. 967)*** (2. 486)** ? 0. 0099 ? 0. 0099 ? 0. 0112 0. 0113 (? 2. 188)** (? 2. 175)** (? 2. 434)** (? 2. 455)** International diversi? cation International diversi? cation squared International diversi? cation ? Advertising intensity International diversi? cation ? R&D intensity Firm size a Debt-to-asset ratio Product diversi? cation Advertising intensity R&D intensity Newness Multiple Time Industry R&D intensity Service Manufacturing Adjusted R2 F value Number of observations a Model 3 Model 4 0. 1476 (2. 236)** ? 0. 0001 ? 0. 0002 (? 0. 336) (? 0. 484) 0. 0072 0. 0071 (1. 531) (1. 516) ? 0. 0001 0. 0000 (? 0. 069) (0. 037) 0. 0667 ? 0. 0147 (2. 100)** (? 0. 04) 0. 0090 0. 0087 (1. 878)* (1. 832)* ? 0. 0003 ? 0. 0002 (? 0. 182) (? 0. 138) 0. 0016 0. 0016 (1. 085) (1. 055) ? 0. 0007 ? 0. 0006 (? 0. 466) (? 0. 407) ? 0. 0034 ? 0. 0032 (? 1. 804)* (? 1. 686)* 0. 0020 ? 0. 0007 (0. 032) (? 1. 121) ? 0. 0005 ? 0. 0015 (? 0. 079) (? 0. 252) 0. 0051 0. 0064 2. 20*** 2. 41*** 3061 3061 Model 6 0. 0036 (0. 637) 0. 1629 (2. 458)** 0. 0295 0. 0003 (0. 676) 0. 0073 (1. 569) ? 0. 0009 (? 0. 744) 0. 0527 (1. 673)* 0. 0093 (1. 941)* ? 0. 0004 (? 0. 195) 0. 0017 (1. 141) ? 0. 0006 (? 0. 389) ? 0. 0018 (? 0. 977) ? 0. 0030 (? 0. 519) ? 0. 0012 (? 0. 218) 0. 0005 1. 15 3061 Model 5Model 7 Model 8 Model 9 0. 0022 0. 0032 0. 0030 0. 0042 (0. 392) (0. 567) (0. 517) (0. 726) 0. 0178 0. 0174 0. 0192 0. 0189 (3. 156)*** (3. 081)*** (3. 375)*** (3. 326)*** ? 0. 0099 ? 0. 0099 ? 0. 0112 ? 0. 0113 (? 2. 188)** (? 2. 175)** (? 2. 434)** (? 2. 455)** 0. 1476 (2. 236)** 0. 0333 (1. 978)** (2. 225)** ? 0. 0001 ? 0. 0002 (? 0. 257) (? 0. 410) 0. 0085 0. 0086 (1. 803)* (1. 824)* ? 0. 0001 0. 0000 (? 0. 102) (0. 012) 0. 0709 ? 0. 0185 (2. 226)** (? 0. 383) 0. 0056 0. 0049 (1. 107) (0. 971) ? 0. 0002 ? 0. 0001 (? 0. 109) (? 0. 051) 0. 0018 0. 0018 (1. 221) (1. 2061) ? 0. 0009 ? 0. 0009 (? 0. 641) (? 0. 99) ? 0. 0046 ? 0. 0046 (? 2. 341)** (? 2. 302)** ? 0. 0005 ? 0. 0016 (? 0. 082) (? 0. 265) ? 0. 0015 ? 0. 0027 (? 0. 252) (? 0. 463) 0. 0060 0. 0077 2. 33*** 2. 58*** 3061 3061 0. 1629 (2. 458)** 0. 0295 0. 0003 (0. 676) 0. 0073 (1. 569) ? 0. 0009 (? 0. 744) 0. 0527 (1. 673)* 0. 0093 (1. 941)* ? 0. 0004 (? 0. 195) 0. 0017 (1. 141) ? 0. 0006 (? 0. 389) ? 0. 0018 (? 0. 977) ? 0. 0003 (? 0. 519) ? 0. 0012 (? 0. 218) 0. 0005 1. 15 3061 Model 10 (1. 978)** ? 0. 0001 ? 0. 0002 ? 0. 0001 (? 0. 336) (? 0. 484) (? 0. 257) 0. 0072 0. 0071 0. 0085 (1. 531) (1. 516) (1. 803)* ? 0. 0001 0. 0000 ? 0. 0001 (? 0. 069) (0. 37) (? 0. 102) 0. 0667 0. 0817 0. 0709 (2. 100)** (2. 517)** (2. 226)** 0. 0090 0. 0087 0. 0249 (1. 878)* (1. 832)* (2. 659)*** ? 0. 0003 ? 0. 0002 ? 0. 0002 (? 0. 182) (? 0. 138) (? 0. 109) 0. 0016 0. 0016 0. 0018 (1. 085) (1. 055) (1. 221) ? 0. 0007 ? 0. 0006 ? 0. 0009 (? 0. 466) (? 0. 407) (? 0. 641) ? 0. 0034 ? 0. 0032 ? 0. 0046 (? 1. 804)* (? 1. 686)* (? 2. 341)** 0. 0020 ? 0. 0007 ? 0. 0005 (0. 032) (? 1. 121) (? 0. 082) ? 0. 0005 ? 0. 0015 ? 0. 0015 (? 0. 079) (? 0. 252) (? 0. 252) 0. 0051 0. 0064 0. 0060 2. 20*** 2. 41*** 2. 33*** 3061 3061 3061 0. 0333 (2. 225)** ? 0. 0002 (? 0. 410) 0. 0086 (1. 824)*
Subscribe to:
Post Comments (Atom)
No comments:
Post a Comment